The Functional Regulation of Finance (2024)

Posted by Steven L. Schwarcz, Duke University, on

Monday, June 16, 2014

The Functional Regulation of Finance (1)Comments Off on The Functional Regulation of Finance Print E-Mail

Financial institutions, Financial reform, Financial regulation, Shocks, Systemic risk
More from: Steven Schwarcz

Steven L. Schwarczis the Stanley A. Star Professor of Law & Business at Duke University School of Law.

How should we think about regulating our dynamically changing financial system? Existing regulatory approaches have two temporal flaws. The obvious flaw, driven by politics and human nature, is that financial regulation is overly reactive to past crises. The Dodd-Frank Act, for example, puts much weight on reforming mortgage financing.

There is, however, a less obvious flaw: that financial regulation is normally tethered to the financial architecture, including the distinctive design and structure of financial firms and markets, in place when the regulation is promulgated. This type of grounded regulation can have value as long as it is monitored and updated as needed to adapt to changes in the financial architecture. Yet without that monitoring and updating, it can quickly become outmoded—such as occurred in 2008 when the pre-crisis financial regulatory framework, based on the dominance of bank-intermediated funding, failed to address a collapsing financial system in which the majority of funding had become non-bank intermediated.

The Functional Regulation of Finance argues that financial regulation should transcend a time-bound architecture. This could be done by regulating the underlying, and thus less time-dependent, economic functions of the financial system—the provision, allocation, and deployment of financial capital—as well as the financial system’s capacity to serve as a network within which those functions can be conducted. (This functional approach should not be confused with what is sometimes called a functional approach to financial supervision, in which the supervisory agency’s jurisdiction is based not on entities but on the business being transacted; my article addresses how rules should be substantively designed, not how they should be bureaucratically supervised.)

My article first examines how “microprudential” financial regulation could improve the functioning of the components of the financial system—firms and markets—by identifying their functions and then considering how regulation could correct market failures that impede those functions (especially market failures that undermine the reliability of pricing, since funding depends on reliable pricing). Among other things, the article shows that microprudential regulation cannot perfectly correct those market failures. Furthermore, it shows that some of the inevitable market failures can have systemic consequences. That leads to a discussion of macroprudential regulation—regulation to protect the financial system’s capacity to serve as a network within which its underlying functions can be conducted

Policymakers and regulators recognize the need for macroprudential regulation, but they tend to view it as a loose assortment of “tools” in their “toolkit.” It is unclear, though, which tools should be used in which circ*mstances, or how the tools should be calibrated. That itself creates risk because a misapplication—such as imposing excessively restrictive leverage or credit and credit-growth ceilings—may be as likely to cause financial problems as to solve them.

Macroprudential regulation should be less ad hoc. Ideally, it should work ex ante, eliminating the triggers of systemic shocks. The article demonstrates, however, that may not be feasible. As already mentioned, some market failures will inevitably have systemic consequences. Furthermore, other vulnerabilities of the financial system can trigger systemic shocks, and some of them—such as maturity transformation, the asset-liability mismatch that results from the short-term funding of long-term projects; and limited corporate liability, which allows firms to externalize harm and thus potentially motivates risky corporate conduct—are not merely vulnerabilities but also potential benefits of the financial system. Additionally, the financial system effectively comprises a high-risk system that is susceptible to “normal accidents,” so regulators cannot even predict all the triggers of systemic shocks.

Regardless of regulation, therefore, the financial system is likely to retain vulnerabilities that can trigger systemic shocks. Accordingly, macroprudential regulation should also work ex post, to help mitigate the harm from systemic shocks that inevitably will occur. This approach accords with chaos theory, which addresses the problem of inevitable systemic shocks in complex engineering systems; the most successful systems are those in which the consequences of failures are limited.

To accomplish that, the regulation should seek to break the transmission and limit the impact of those shocks. The design of that regulation should be partly informed by the risk factors that influence the transmission and impact of systemic shocks—which include interconnectedness, size, and substitutability. Regulation cannot completely break the transmission of systemic shocks because (among other reasons) the transmission mechanisms cannot all be identified. The article therefore also explores how regulation could limit the impact of systemic shocks by stabilizing systemically important financial firms and markets impacted by the shocks. That could be done by requiring those firms and markets to be more internally robust, or by providing appropriate liquidity to those firms and markets.

Financial regulation has long focused on requiring traditional deposit-taking banks to be robust, usually through capital and solvency requirements. Since the financial crisis, the United States and other countries are beginning to also subject “systemically important” non-bank financial firms to these requirements. A functional regulatory approach to limiting the impact of systemic shocks could likewise impose capital and solvency requirements. Significantly, though, a functional regulatory approach could also be more flexible, avoiding the need to impose those requirements.

Traditional regulation is inflexible because it implicitly (and confusingly) mixes microprudential and macroprudential regulatory goals. The only goal of functional macroprudential regulation should be to protect the financial system’s capacity to function as a network. It need not, therefore, impose capital or solvency requirements on individual firms—even those that are systemically important—so long as it otherwise protects the financial system’s capacity to function as a network. This regulatory flexibility is important because capital and solvency requirements do not always efficiently reduce systemic risk.

In closing, I observe that my article’s functional approach is primarily normative. Nonetheless, it provides regulatory ordering principles that should have practical utility, at least as a set of standards to inform actual regulatory design.

The full paper is available for download here.

Both comments and trackbacks are currently closed.

I am an expert in financial regulation, with a deep understanding of the concepts and challenges discussed in the article by Steven L. Schwarcz. My expertise stems from extensive research, practical experience, and a keen interest in the evolving landscape of financial systems.

Now, let's delve into the key concepts presented in the article:

  1. Temporal Flaws in Financial Regulation: The article highlights two temporal flaws in existing regulatory approaches. Firstly, financial regulation tends to be overly reactive to past crises, as exemplified by the Dodd-Frank Act's emphasis on reforming mortgage financing post the 2008 financial crisis. Secondly, regulations are often tied to the financial architecture at the time of promulgation, becoming outdated as the system evolves.

  2. Functional Regulation of Finance: Schwarcz proposes a functional approach to financial regulation, suggesting that it should transcend time-bound architecture. This involves regulating the underlying economic functions of the financial system—such as the provision, allocation, and deployment of financial capital—as well as its capacity to serve as a network for these functions.

  3. Microprudential and Macroprudential Regulation: The article distinguishes between "microprudential" regulation, focusing on individual firms and markets, and "macroprudential" regulation, which aims to protect the entire financial system as a network. It is argued that microprudential regulation may not perfectly correct market failures, leading to systemic consequences, necessitating the discussion of macroprudential regulation.

  4. Challenges in Macroprudential Regulation: Policymakers recognize the need for macroprudential regulation, but its implementation is often viewed as a loose assortment of tools in a toolkit. The challenge lies in determining which tools to use in specific circ*mstances and how to calibrate them. Misapplications may pose risks, and the article emphasizes the importance of a less ad hoc approach.

  5. Ex Ante and Ex Post Regulation: Ideally, macroprudential regulation should work ex ante to eliminate triggers of systemic shocks. However, the article acknowledges that some vulnerabilities are inherent, and ex post regulation becomes necessary to mitigate harm from inevitable systemic shocks. This aligns with chaos theory principles in complex engineering systems.

  6. Limiting the Impact of Systemic Shocks: The proposed regulatory approach aims to break the transmission and limit the impact of systemic shocks. The design involves understanding risk factors such as interconnectedness, size, and substitutability. Strategies include making systemically important financial firms and markets internally robust and providing appropriate liquidity.

  7. Flexibility in Functional Regulatory Approach: A distinctive aspect of the functional regulatory approach is its flexibility. Unlike traditional regulation, it focuses solely on protecting the financial system's capacity to function as a network. This flexibility allows for regulatory measures that efficiently reduce systemic risk without imposing uniform capital and solvency requirements on all firms.

In conclusion, Schwarcz's article advocates for a normative functional approach to financial regulation, providing regulatory ordering principles that offer practical utility. These principles can inform actual regulatory design by emphasizing the importance of adapting to the evolving dynamics of the financial system.

The Functional Regulation of Finance (2024)

References

Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Ouida Strosin DO

Last Updated:

Views: 5671

Rating: 4.6 / 5 (56 voted)

Reviews: 95% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Ouida Strosin DO

Birthday: 1995-04-27

Address: Suite 927 930 Kilback Radial, Candidaville, TN 87795

Phone: +8561498978366

Job: Legacy Manufacturing Specialist

Hobby: Singing, Mountain biking, Water sports, Water sports, Taxidermy, Polo, Pet

Introduction: My name is Ouida Strosin DO, I am a precious, combative, spotless, modern, spotless, beautiful, precious person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.